The Week In The Eurozone: Efforts Begin To Pay Off

 | Dec 23, 2012 05:29AM ET

The eurozone’s peripheral countries have embarked on a long and difficult adjustment process, but it is beginning to pay off. This can be seen in the absorption of current account deficits in several countries. In Spain, Ireland and Portugal, current account balances have almost swung back to or have surpassed the levels that prevailed when they joined economic and monetary union (EMU). Of the eurozone’s 17 member states, only Greece and Cyprus are still reporting current account deficits higher than the European Commission’s benchmark (-4% of GDP).

Of course, these adjustments largely reflect the drop off in imports that accompanied the decline in purchasing power and domestic demand. But that is not the only factor at play. In Spain, for example, exports are now 12% higher than the pre-crisis peak, a performance that surpasses Germany. Indeed, rising exports and declining domestic demand are two trends that cannot be disassociated: although the goal of the internal devaluation process is to restore competitiveness, it cannot be achieved without adjusting domestic demand.

Eurostat data published this week show that labour cost adjustments are continuing in the eurozone’s peripheral countries. In Q3 2012, Spanish unit labour costs declined for the second consecutive quarter by more than 3% yoy, while in Greece the decline was still nearly 6% yoy. Q3 data are not available yet for Portugal, but unit labour cost adjustment process accelerated in previous quarters.

To be effective, the decline in unit labour costs (in absolute terms or relative to its main competitors) must result in a decline in output prices. In the export sector, price declines are all the more important for countries specialising in low value-added goods, for which price competitiveness plays a key role (this is often the case for the countries under review). Yet prices of non-tradable goods and services must also be adjusted.

First, this helps limit the loss of purchasing power induced by lower wages. Second, it is crucial that the profitability of these protected sectors does not improve relative to export sectors, much to the contrary. The reallocation of domestic resources to export sectors is necessary in the medium-term to invest in product lines, expand the industrial base, and strengthen and consolidate the gains in competitiveness achieved through devaluation.

It is hard to know to what extent the slowdown in unit labour costs is effectively transmitted to prices using the usual inflation data, which does not seem to be significantly weaker in the economies undergoing internal devaluation. Yet these economies are also the ones in which governments have raised indirect taxes the most in recent years to reduce budget deficits (Chart 1).