Low Inflation Expectations Act As A Self-Reinforcing Anchor

 | Oct 04, 2019 07:45AM ET

Memories of high inflation have faded; what does this collective amnesia mean for inflation in the future?

Inflation expectations have drifted lower because society is forgetting about inflation. Indeed, a whole generation has grown up knowing nothing but price stability. This makes it harder for central banks to hit their inflation targets, particularly in Europe where more southerly countries' inflation 'memory' has been subsumed by Germany's experience.

But this has not always been the case.

An entire generation of young adults has grown up since the mid-1960s knowing only of inflation … it is hardly surprising that many citizens have begun to wonder whether it is realistic to anticipate a return to general price stability” – Former Federal Reserve Chair, Paul Volcker (1979)

40 years ago, Volcker worried that persistently high and rising inflation had de-anchored inflation expectations. A policy-induced recession was ultimately required to drive them back down.

We're in the opposite situation today. We've had 25 years – a whole generation – of low US inflation, depressing inflation expectations.

This explains one of today's macro puzzles: why wage inflation remains subdued despite low unemployment . Once we adjust for record-low inflation expectations, households' perceived 'real' wages are growing as rapidly as in previous economic booms.

But low inflation expectations act as a self-reinforcing anchor for nominal variables, hampering central banks' ability to hit their inflation remits.

A whole generation has grown up knowing nothing but price stability

Micro evidence suggests 'memory effects' explain the downward drift in inflation expectations.

After the inflation shocks of the 1970s, younger households had higher inflation expectations than older ones. The former were scarred by the successive oil shocks while the latter still remembered the golden era of the 1960s, if not deflationary tales of the Great Depression.

To illustrate this, I have plotted the gap between 'young' (60) people’s inflation expectations in the chart below. It broadly matches the difference between short (10-year) and long-term (50-year) averages of inflation. As inflation trends above historical norms, younger people will have higher inflation expectations than older ones (and vice versa).