How The Fed Is Suffocating The Economy

 | Jan 28, 2016 07:46AM ET

Investors are worried over the prospects that the long-term momentum behind the stock market recovery of 2009-2015 may be in danger of complete dissipation this year. That would mean a certain date with an extended bear market and, potentially, an economic recession perhaps sometime later this year.

Normally, within the context of an established bull market, worry would be a good thing given that the bull tends to proceed along a “wall of worry.” In view of recent actions undertaken by central banks, however, those worries are legitimate as I’ll explain in this commentary.

There are two established ways of killing forward momentum and induce economic recession. One is to sharply reverse monetary policy or margin maintenance policy from very loose to very tight. An example of this is what happened in the months leading up to the 1929 crash; yet another example was the margin requirement tightening in the gold, silver and copper markets in 2011.

The other way of reversing forward momentum is to slowly suffocate the financial market through subtle, incremental policy shifts which favor holding cash over equities. The central banks of Europe and the U.S. have opted for the latter course. The ultimate outcome of this policy are being felt even now in Europe and elsewhere, but likely won’t become abundantly clear in the U.S. until later this year.

Tight money policy, especially at a time when the financial market is vulnerable to overseas weakness, is nothing short of a recipe for disaster. Timothy Cogley, an economist with the San Francisco Federal Reserve Bank, admitted in a 1999 research paper that the Fed’s tight monetary policy in 1928-29 likely contributed to the stock market crash of 1929. Cogley observed:

“In 1928 there was a synchronized, global contraction of monetary policy, which occurred primarily because the Fed was concerned about stock prices. These actions had predictable effects on economic activity. By the second quarter of 1929 it was apparent that economic activity was slowing. The U.S. economy peaked in August and fell into a recession in September.” [“Monetary Policy and the Great Crash of 1929: A Bursting Bubble or Collapsing Fundamentals?”]

The Fed’s mistake in those days was in trying to prevent a speculative bubble in the equity market. In so doing, however, the Fed inadvertently contributed to an even greater problem: the implosion of a speculative bubble. Moreover, the speculative bubble was fueled in part by a loose monetary policy in the years leading up to the 1928-29 run up in stock prices.

Cogley concluded: “In retrospect, it seems that the lesson of the Great Crash is more about the difficulty of identifying speculative bubbles and the risks associated with aggressive actions conditioned on noisy observations. In the critical years 1928 to 1930, the Fed did not stand on the sidelines and allow asset prices to soar unabated. On the contrary, its policy represented a striking example of The Economist’s recommendation: a deliberate, preemptive strike against an (apparent) bubble. The Fed succeeded in putting a halt to the rapid increase in share prices, but in doing so it may have contributed one of the main impulses for the Great Depression.”

Get The News You Want
Read market moving news with a personalized feed of stocks you care about.
Get The App

While the Fed’s recent quarter-point interest rate increase may seem insignificant at face value, the magnitude of the move can only be appreciated by realizing the rate of change involved. The following graph provides some idea of just how huge in percentage terms the Fed’s policy tightening is.