Origins Of The ‘Rising Dollar’

 | Aug 24, 2016 01:52AM ET

On March 9, 2016, front month trading for Japanese government bond (JGB) futures was halted at 12:32 pm Tokyo time. Selling had become intense, tripping the Osaka Exchange’s dynamic circuit breaker. The total length of the halt was just 30 seconds, but fingers were already being pointed in the direction of the BoJ.

More than four months later, on July 28, trading was halted in all products for JGB’s for an estimated 20 minutes starting 9:51 am Tokyo time. While the exchange provided very little information, they eventually blamed a delay in system processing. Whether or not that was the proximate cause doesn’t really matter, as the context for the trading darkness was just hours ahead of BoJ’s latest monetary policy decision.

A few days after that, on August 2, JGB 10s experienced their worst single day selloff in 13 years. That ended a 3-day selling binge that cut 2.47 points off the price of the 10-year benchmark, the largest three-day losing streak since May 2013 shortly after QQE had begun.

You might get the sense from these events that trading liquidity in JGB’s, cash or futures, isn’t exactly the most robust these days. Violent swings in bond markets are never a good thing in either direction (just ask the US Treasury ). It’s not just government bonds, however, that have obtained a direct and palpable disdain from institutions that used to be a major part of the financial plumbing in Japan.

On March 8, just one day before the first JGB futures halt, every single one of the eleven Japanese asset managers that provided money market funds announced plans to close them to new investors and then repay their existing liabilities throughout the rest of this year. The money market business was over in Japan. In late February, fund sponsors had appealed to BoJ for a special exemption to overcome the sudden imposition of NIRP the month before but were rebuffed. There is far less in Japanese money market funds than in the US or Europe, so it wasn’t ever going to rise to the level of something like a systemic run but that isn’t Japan’s biggest risk in the wake of NIRP.

As money market funds shut down, so, too, did total interbank activity in the money markets. The Wall Street Journal reported in mid-April that:

Trading has withered in Japan’s money markets, where big banks and others usually park their excess cash hoping to receive some interest—despite predictions from the Bank of Japan that its latest easing of monetary policy would spark more activity. And there has been a rush in demand for Japanese government bonds even as many yields went below zero.

Somehow, despite this corruption in one of the central points of the modern wholesale financial system, the Journal manages to both call it the “latest easing of monetary policy” while also stating in the article’s introduction that this withering was an “unexpected” result of such “easing.” It’s an insult upon their readers’ intelligence to maintain orthodox shorthand in the very data and evidence that disproves both “easing” and “unexpected.”

Get The News You Want
Read market moving news with a personalized feed of stocks you care about.
Get The App

The draining “rush in demand for Japanese government bonds” was entirely predictable, as I wrote a month before in mid-March:

Part of the answer can be found in NIRP itself, as even the BoJ’s three-tiered system only penalizes “idle” bank reserves and only so far. Rolling out of the equivalent of the Japanese deposit account and into a government bond escapes that monetary “tax.” The fact that such an effort is pushing up to 10 years in maturity demonstrates serious distortion (as of March 17, the 15-year JGB is safely positive at 15.7 bps but that yield, too, is pushing lower).

To roll into such long maturity negative yields, however, defies somewhat the point of holding even inert bank “reserves” in the first place. It adds elements of risk into the mix that go beyond trying to find the least costly monetary nothingness. That suggests something else working in concert to Japan’s banks.

In fact, by that point yields on a great deal of the JGB curve were dropping or had dropped below the -10 bps threshold for the NIRP penalty. That is what negative rates intend, meaning they are axiomatically the opposite of “easing” as a matter of basic construction. The Bank of Japan in not finding success it expected out of QQE fully intended to penalize Japanese banks for holding all the reserves that it created as a byproduct of that policy (like the many QE’s before it). Until such time as BoJ and Abenomics decide to just circumvent banks entirely, Japanese institutions still reserve the right to refuse to participate.